nep-mic New Economics Papers
on Microeconomics
Issue of 2013‒01‒12
fifteen papers chosen by
Jing-Yuan Chiou
IMT Lucca Institute for Advanced Studies

  1. Multi-dimensional auctions under information asymmetry for costs and qualities By Papakonstantinou, A.; Bogetoft, P.
  2. Beyond price discrimination: welfare under differential pricing when costs also differ By Chen, Yongmin; Schwartz, Marius
  3. Assortative matching through signals By Poeschel, Friedrich
  4. When to Attack an Oppressive Government? By Bilkic, Natasa; Gries, Thomas
  5. Mixed Equilibrium: When Burning Money is Rational By Souza, Filipe; Rêgo, Leandro
  6. Collaborative Dominance: When Doing Unto Others As You Would Have Them Do Unto You Is Reasonable. By Souza, Filipe; Rêgo, Leandro
  7. Gambling in contests with regret By Han Feng; David Hobson
  8. Robust Optimal Stopping under Volatility Uncertainty By Erhan Bayraktar; Song Yao
  9. Contracting over Prices By Shurojit Chatterji; Sayantan Ghosal
  10. Expectation Damages and Bilateral Cooperative Investments By Göller, Daniel
  11. Taxation and Incomplete Contracts By Simone Moriconi
  12. Utility maximization with current utility on the wealth: regularity of solutions to the HJB equation By Salvatore Federico; Paul Gassiat; Fausto Gozzi
  13. Why Do Voters Dismantle Checks and Balances? Extensions and Robustness. By Ragnar Torvik; Daron Acemoglu; James A. Robinson
  14. The hold-up problem, innovations, and limited liability By Schmitz, Patrick W.
  15. The Two Sides of Envy By Boris Gershman

  1. By: Papakonstantinou, A.; Bogetoft, P.
    Abstract: This paper discusses the design of a novel multi-dimensional mechanism which allows a principal to procure a single project or an item from multiple suppliers through a two-step payment. The suppliers are capable of producing different qualities at costs which cannot exceed a certain value and the mechanism balances between the costs faced by the suppliers and the benefit the principal achieves from higher qualities. Iniatially, the principal implements a standard second score auction and allocates the project to a single supplier based its reported cost and quality, while then it elicits truthful reporting of the quality by issuing a symmetric secondary payment after observing the winner’s production. We then provide an alternate mechanism in which the principal issues an asymmetric secondary payment which rewards agents for producing higher qualities, while it penalises them for producing lower qualities than they reported. We prove that for both mechanisms truthful revelation of costs and qualities is a dominant strategy (weakly for costs) and that they are immune to combined misreporting of both qualities and costs. We also show that the mechanisms are individually rational, and that the optimal payments received by the winners of the auctions are equal to the payment issued by the standard second score auction.
    Keywords: multi-dimensional auctions; procurement; contract theory; auction theory
    JEL: D86 D82
    Date: 2012
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:43563&r=mic
  2. By: Chen, Yongmin; Schwartz, Marius
    Abstract: We extend the analysis of monopoly third-degree price discrimination to the empirically important case where marginal costs also differ between markets. Differential pricing then reallocates output to the lower-cost markets, hence welfare can increase even if total output does not, unlike under pure price discrimination. To induce output reallocation the firm varies its prices but---again, unlike under pure price discrimination---with no upward bias in the average price. Due to this price dispersion, differential pricing motivated solely by cost differences will increase consumer surplus (and total welfare) for a broad class of demand functions. We also provide sufficient conditions for beneficial differential pricing in the hybrid case where both demand elasticities and marginal costs differ.
    Keywords: price discrimination; differential pricing; price dispersion; add-on pricing
    JEL: D4 L1
    Date: 2012–12–23
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:43393&r=mic
  3. By: Poeschel, Friedrich
    Abstract: In a model of sequential search with transferable utility, we allow heterogeneous agents to strategically choose a costless signal of their type. Search frictions are included as discounting and explicit search costs. Through signals, if only they are truthful, agents can avoid the inefficiencies of random search. Then the situation effectively approaches a setting without search frictions. We identify the condition under which signals are truthful and a unique separating equilibrium with perfect sorting arises despite frictions. We find that supermodularity of the match production function is a necessary and sufficient condition. This is a weaker condition than is needed for sorting in models without signals, which may explain why sorting is much more widespread in reality than existing models would suggest. Supermodularity functions here as both a sorting condition and a single-crossing property. The unique separating equilibrium in our model achieves nearly unconstrained efficiency despite frictions: agents successfully conclude their search after a single meeting, a stable matching results, and overall match output is maximised. --
    JEL: J64 D83 C78
    Date: 2012
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:zbw:vfsc12:62061&r=mic
  4. By: Bilkic, Natasa; Gries, Thomas
    Abstract: Initiating a conflict is an investment in social, political or economic change. The decision to attack is sequential in time, irreversible and, more important, includes highly uncertain and erratic threats and opportunities yet completely disregarded in confict theory. In this dynamic model of decision making we focus on the time dimension of an escalating conflict. In order to cover the effects of high uncertainties we extend methods in real option theory by introducing a discontinuous Ito-L vy Jump Diffusion processes. We analytically derive a threshold that triggers the attack and determine the expected time of action. With this new discontinuous processs we are able to show that an increasing number and intensity of oppressive government actions may lead to an earlier outbreak of conflict. However, even if latent conflicts are not immediately solved policies can prolong the peace period to find a long term solution to the conflict. --
    JEL: D74 D81 C61
    Date: 2012
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:zbw:vfsc12:62031&r=mic
  5. By: Souza, Filipe; Rêgo, Leandro
    Abstract: We discuss the rationality of burning money behavior from a new perspective: the mixed Nash equilibrium. We support our argument analyzing the first-order derivatives of the mixed equilibrium expected utility of the players with respect to their own utility payoffs in a 2x2 normal form game. We establish necessary and sufficient conditions that guarantee the existence of negative derivatives. In particular, games with negative derivatives are the ones that create incentives for burning money behavior since such behavior in these games improves the player’s mixed equilibrium expected utility. We show that a negative derivative for the mixed equilibrium expected utility of a given player i occurs if, and only if, he has a strict preference for one of the strategies of the other player. Moreover, negative derivatives always occur when they are taken with respect to player i’s highest and lowest game utility payoffs.
    Keywords: Mixed Nash Equilibrium; Burning Money; Collaborative Dominance; Security Dilemma
    JEL: C7
    Date: 2012–02–10
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:43410&r=mic
  6. By: Souza, Filipe; Rêgo, Leandro
    Abstract: In this article, we analyze how reasonable it is to play according to some Nash equilibria if players have a preference for one of their opponents’ strategies. For this, we propose the concepts of collaborative dominance and collaborative equilibrium. First we prove that, when the collaborative equilibrium exists it is always efficient, what can be seen as a focal property. Further we argue that a reason for players choosing not to collaborate is if they are focusing in security instead of efficiency, in which case they would prefer to play maximin strategies. This argument allows us to reduce the hall of reasonable equilibria for games where a collaborative equilibrium exists. Finally, we point out that two-player zero-sum games do not have collaborative equilibrium and, moreover, if there exists a strategy profile formed only by collaboratively dominated actions it is a Nash equilibrium in such kind of game.
    Keywords: Nash Equilibrium; Collaborative Dominance; Two-Players Zero-Sum Games
    JEL: C7
    Date: 2012–11–20
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:43408&r=mic
  7. By: Han Feng; David Hobson
    Abstract: This paper discusses the gambling contest introduced in Seel & Strack (Gambling in contests, Discussion Paper Series of SFB/TR 15 Governance and the Efficiency of Economic Systems 375, Mar 2012.) and considers the impact of adding a penalty associated with failure to follow a winning strategy. The Seel & Strack model consists of $n$-agents each of whom privately observes a transient diffusion process and chooses when to stop it. The player with the highest stopped value wins the contest, and each player's objective is to maximise their probability of winning the contest. We give a new derivation of the results of Seel & Strack based on a Lagrangian approach. Moreover, we consider an extension of the problem in which in the case when an agent is penalised when their strategy is suboptimal, in the sense that they do not win the contest, but there existed an alternative strategy which would have resulted in victory.
    Date: 2013–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:arx:papers:1301.0719&r=mic
  8. By: Erhan Bayraktar; Song Yao
    Abstract: We analyze a robust optimal stopping problem when there is volatility uncertainty. This is a zero-sum controller-stopper game in which the stopper is trying to maximize its pay-off against an adverse player which tries to minimize this payoff by choosing the probability measure by from a set of measures which are not necessarily equivalent. In particular, we analyze the upper Snell envelope $\ol{Z}$ of the reward process $Y$ and by comparing it with the Snell envelope of $Y$ under each individual probability $\hP$, we show that $\ol{Z}$ is an $\ul{\sE}_t \dfnn \underset{\hP \in \cQ_t}{\inf} \hE_\hP [\cd]$-supermartingale, and a nonlinear martingale up to the first time $\t^*$ when $\ol{Z}$ meets $Y$. Consequently, $\t^*$ is the optimal stopping time for the robust optimal stopping problem.
    Date: 2013–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:arx:papers:1301.0091&r=mic
  9. By: Shurojit Chatterji (Singapore Management University, School of Economics); Sayantan Ghosal (Warwick University)
    Abstract: We define a solution concept, perfectly contracted equilibrium, for an intertempo- ral exchange economy where agents are simultaneously price takers in spot commod- ity markets while engaging in ecient, non-Walrasian contracting over future prices. Without requiring that agents have perfect foresight, we show that perfectly contracted equilibrium outcomes are a subset of Pareto optimal allocations. It is a robust possi- bility for perfectly contracted equilibrium outcomes to differ from Arrow-Debreu equi- librium outcomes. We show that both centralized banking and retrading with bilateral contracting can lead to perfectly contracted equilibria.
    Keywords: equilibrium, future prices, uncertainty, contracts
    JEL: D5 D70 D72 D84
    Date: 2012–12
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:siu:wpaper:36-2012&r=mic
  10. By: Göller, Daniel
    Abstract: We examine the efficiency of the standard breach remedy expectation damages in a setting of bilateral cooperative investment by a buyer and a seller. Contracts may specify a required quality level and an upper bound to the cost of production. We find that it is optimal to write an augmented Cadillac contract that sets one threshold such that it cannot be met with positive probability together with an extreme price. Then, one of the parties becomes a residual claimant of the trade relationship. The other threshold can be used to balance the incentives of the other party. --
    JEL: K12 C70 D86
    Date: 2012
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:zbw:vfsc12:62047&r=mic
  11. By: Simone Moriconi (ITEMQ, Università Cattolica di Milano and CREA, University of Luxembourg)
    Abstract: This paper analyzes the impact of taxation on economic effciency when contracts are incomplete. We assume firms operate in a perfect competitive market and can choose between integrated or non-integrated governance to cope with contract incompleteness. Taxation reduces incentives to pursue intra-firm coordination, thus the effciency of firm's production process under non-integration. This is not the case under integration, since production decisions are transferred to the Headquarters, at a fixed integration cost. Taxation may then induce firms to change their organization at the industry equilibrium. We show that a tax that induces firms to choose integration rather than non-integration may serve a corrective function if integration costs and market prices are not too high.
    Keywords: taxation, incomplete contracts and economic effciency
    JEL: H21 L22 H32
    Date: 2012
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:luc:wpaper:12-08&r=mic
  12. By: Salvatore Federico; Paul Gassiat; Fausto Gozzi
    Abstract: We consider a utility maximization problem for an investment-consumption portfolio when the current utility depends also on the wealth process. Such kind of problems arise, e.g., in portfolio optimization with random horizon or with random trading times. To overcome the difficulties of the problem we use the dual approach. We define a dual problem and treat it by means of dynamic programming, showing that the viscosity solutions of the associated Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation belong to a suitable class of smooth functions. This allows to define a smooth solution of the primal Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equation, proving that this solution is indeed unique in a suitable class and coincides with the value function of the primal problem. Some financial applications of the results are provided.
    Date: 2013–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:arx:papers:1301.0280&r=mic
  13. By: Ragnar Torvik (Department of Economics, Norwegian University of Science and Technology); Daron Acemoglu; James A. Robinson
    Abstract: In this online appendix we extend the basic model in the paper in several directions, discuss the robustness of the results, and moreover what new mechanisms our extensions implies as compared to the ones in the basic model.
    Date: 2013–01–04
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nst:samfok:14013&r=mic
  14. By: Schmitz, Patrick W.
    Abstract: An inventor can invest research effort to come up with an innovation. Once an innovation is made, a contract is negotiated and unobservable effort must be exerted to develop a product. In the absence of liability constraints, the inventor's investment incentives are increasing in his bargaining power. Yet, given limited liability, overinvestments may occur and the inventor's investment incentives may be decreasing in his bargaining power.
    Keywords: hold-up problem; incomplete contracts; research and development; limited liability
    JEL: D86 L23 O31
    Date: 2012–12
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:43407&r=mic
  15. By: Boris Gershman
    Abstract: The two sides of envy, destructive and constructive, give rise to qualitatively dierent equi-libria, depending on the economic, institutional, and cultural environment. If investment opportunities are scarce, inequality is high, property rights are poorly protected, and social comparisons are strong, society is likely to be in the fear equilibrium," in which better endowed agents restrain their eorts to prevent destructive envy of the relatively poor. Otherwise, the standard \keeping up with the Joneses" competition arises, and envy is satised through suboptimally high eorts. Economic growth expands the production possibilities frontier and triggers an endogenous transition from one equilibrium to the other causing a qualitative shift in the relationship between envy and economic performance: envy-avoidance behavior with its adverse eect on investment paves the way to creative emulation. From a welfare perspective, better institutions and wealth redistribution that move the society away from the low-output fear equilibrium need not be Pareto improving in the short run, as they unleash the negative consumption externality, but in the long run such policies are likely to increase social welfare due to enhanced productivity growth.
    Keywords: Economic growth, Envy, Inequality, Property rights, Redistribution
    JEL: D31 D62 D74 O10 O43 Z13
    Date: 2012
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:amu:wpaper:2012-19&r=mic

This nep-mic issue is ©2013 by Jing-Yuan Chiou. It is provided as is without any express or implied warranty. It may be freely redistributed in whole or in part for any purpose. If distributed in part, please include this notice.
General information on the NEP project can be found at http://nep.repec.org. For comments please write to the director of NEP, Marco Novarese at <director@nep.repec.org>. Put “NEP” in the subject, otherwise your mail may be rejected.
NEP’s infrastructure is sponsored by the School of Economics and Finance of Massey University in New Zealand.