|
on Experimental Economics |
By: | Werner Güth (Max Planck Insitute of Economics, Jena); Lauri Sääksvuori (Max Planck Insitute of Economics, Jena) |
Abstract: | This article examines the nature of human behavior in a nested social dilemma referred to as the Spillover Game. Players are divided into two groups with positive production interdependencies. Based on theoretically derived opportunistic, local, and global optima, our experimental results demonstrate the importance of in-group beneficiaries over global efficiency. We find that the observed behavior is primarily determined by an imperfect conditional cooperation that prioritizes local level feedback. Results stress the importance of building strong local level commitment to encourage the provision of public goods with positive externalities. |
Keywords: | Public good, experiment, groups, Spillover Game, social dilemma |
JEL: | H41 C72 C91 C92 |
Date: | 2010–03–25 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:jrp:jrpwrp:2010-022&r=exp |
By: | Nicolas Jacquemet (Centre d'Economie de la Sorbonne - Paris School of Economics); Alexander G. James (University of Wyoming - Department of Economics); Stéphane Luchini (Groupe de Recherche en Economie Quantitative d'Aix-Marseille); Jason F. Shogren (University of Wyoming - Department of Economics) |
Abstract: | Environmental economics is now a long standing field of research ; much has been learned on how environmental policy can use incentives to drive individual behaviors. Among the many examples, preference elicitation is the most discussed case in which incentives fail to accurately implement efficient behavior. Using this as our motivating example, herein we explore the cross-fertilization between environmental economics and social psychology. We first review how the lessons drawn from social psychology helped address the hypothetical bias issue. We then turn to the future of this process by focusing on how cheap talk scripts influence preference elicitation. Our experimental results shows CT scripts work through persuasion – i.e. changes mind, but poorly changes actions. in that sense, preference elicitation still lacks a way of making communication binding – i.e. a way to alter intrinsic motivation of subjects to behave truthfully. |
Keywords: | Social psychology, commitment, persuasive communication, preference elicitation. |
JEL: | C9 H4 Q5 |
Date: | 2010–02 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:mse:cesdoc:10016&r=exp |
By: | Gill, David; Prowse, Victoria |
Abstract: | We develop a novel computerized real effort task, based on moving sliders across a screen, to test experimentally whether agents are disappointment averse when they compete in a real effort sequential-move tournament. We predict that a disappointment averse agent, who is loss averse around her endogenous choice-acclimating expectations-based reference point, responds negatively to her rival's effort. We find significant evidence for this discouragement effect, and use the Method of Simulated Moments to estimate the strength of disappointment aversion on average and the heterogeneity in disappointment aversion across the population. <br><br> Keynames; Disappointment aversion; Loss aversion; Reference-dependent preferences; Reference point adjustment; Expectations; Tournament; Real effort experiment; Slider task. <br><br> JEL Classification: C91; D03. |
Date: | 2010–03–01 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:stn:sotoec:1006&r=exp |
By: | Kocher, Martin G. (University of Munich); Lenz, Marc V. (University of Cologne); Sutter, Matthias (University of Innsbruck) |
Abstract: | Apesteguia and Palacios-Huerta (forthcoming) report for a sample of 129 shootouts from various seasons in ten different competitions that teams kicking first in soccer penalty shootouts win significantly more often than teams kicking second. Collecting data for the entire history of six major soccer competitions we cannot replicate their result. Teams kicking first win only 53.4% of 262 shootouts in our data, which is not significantly different from random. Our findings have two implications: (1) Apesteguia and Palacios-Huerta's results are not generally robust. (2) Using specific subsamples without a coherent criterion for data selection might lead to non-representative findings. |
Keywords: | tournament, first-mover advantage, psychological pressure, field experiment, soccer, penalty shootouts |
JEL: | C93 |
Date: | 2010–03 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:iza:izadps:dp4846&r=exp |
By: | Bauernschuster, Stefan; Duersch, Peter; Oechssler, Jörg; Vadovic, Radovan |
Abstract: | Sick-pay is a common provision in labor contracts. It insures workers against a sudden loss of income due to unexpected absences and helps them smooth consumption. Therefore, many governments find sick-pay socially desirable and choose to mandate its provision. But sick-pay is not without its problems. Not only it suffers from moral hazard but more importantly it is subject to a potentially serious adverse selection problem (higher sick-pay attracts sicker workers). In this paper we report results of an experiment which inquires to the extend and the severity of the adverse selection when sick-pay is voluntary versus when it is mandatory. Theoretically, mandating sick-pay may be effective in diminishing adverse selection. However, our data provide clean evidence that counteracting effects are more salient. Mandatory sick pay exacerbates moral hazard problems by changing fairness perceptions and, as a consequence, increases sick pay provision far above the mandatory levels. |
Keywords: | sick pay; sick leave; experiment; gift exchange. |
JEL: | C9 C7 J3 |
Date: | 2010–03–30 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:awi:wpaper:0498&r=exp |
By: | Ilja Neustadt (Socioeconomic Institute, University of Zurich); Peter Zweifel (Socioeconomic Institute, University of Zurich) |
Abstract: | The sustainability of the welfare state ultimately depends on citizens’ preferences for income redistribution. They are elicited through a Discrete Choice Experiment performed in 2008 in Switzerland. Attributes are redistribution as GDP share, its uses (the unemployed, old-age pensioners, people with ill health etc.), and nationality of beneficiary. Estimated marginal willingness to pay (WTP) is positive among those who deem benefits too low, and negative otherwise. However, even those who state that government should reduce income inequality exhibit a negative WTP on average. The major finding is that estimated average WTP is maximum at 21% of GDP, clearly below the current value of 25%. Thus, the present Swiss welfare state does not appear sustainable. |
Keywords: | Income redistribution, preferences, willingness to pay, welfare state, sustainability, discrete choice experiments, |
JEL: | C35 C93 D63 H29 |
Date: | 2010–03 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:soz:wpaper:1003&r=exp |
By: | Kontek, Krzysztof |
Abstract: | This paper deals with estimating data from experiments determining lottery certainty equivalents. The paper presents the parametric and nonparametric results of the least squares (mean), quantile (including median) and mode estimations. The examined data are found to be positively skewed for low probabilities and negatively skewed for high probabilities. This observation leads to the striking conclusion that lottery valuations are only nonlinearly related to probability when means are considered. Such nonlinearity is not confirmed by the mode estimator in which case the most likely lottery valuations are close to their expected values. This means that the most likely behavior of a group is fully rational. This conclusion is a significant departure from one of the fundamental results concerning lottery experiments presented so far. |
Keywords: | Lottery experiments; Least Squares; Quantile; Median; and Mode Estimators; Nonparametric and Parametric Estimators; Relative Utility Function; Prospect Theory. |
JEL: | C51 D81 C91 C13 C14 C81 C21 C01 D87 |
Date: | 2010–03–30 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:21758&r=exp |
By: | Todd McElroy; David L. Dickinson |
Abstract: | Research investigating risk preference has pointed towards motivation and ability as important factors for determining the strength and likelihood of the framing effect. In the current study we explored the influence of individual differences in motivation and ability through circadian rhythm. We predicted that during circadian off-times participants would exhibit stronger framing effects whereas framing effects would be relatively weaker during on-times. Six-hundred and eighty five individuals took part in the study; the findings supported our hypothesis, revealing a diurnal pattern of risk responding that varies across the 24-hour circadian cycle. Key Words: |
Date: | 2010 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:apl:wpaper:10-06&r=exp |
By: | Estrada, Fernando |
Abstract: | In their recent work Thomas S. Schelling (2007, 2010), reiterating original arguments about game theory and its applications to social sciences. In particular, game theory helps to explore situations in which agents make decisions interdependent (strategic communication). Schelling's originality is to extend economic theory to social sciences. When a player can anticipate the options and influence the decisions of others. The strategy, indirect communication plays a crucial role. To illustrate, we investigate how to perform the payoff matrix in cases of bribery and threat |
Keywords: | Social Science; Schelling; game theory; strategic communications; bribes; threats. |
JEL: | B0 D81 A1 D82 C70 C7 B00 D84 D7 D8 D80 C72 |
Date: | 2010–03–30 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:21772&r=exp |